Switch to: References

Add citations

You must login to add citations.
  1. The Inefficiency of Some Efficiency Comparisons: A Reply to Nye.Edward Saraydar - 1990 - Economics and Philosophy 6 (1):153-155.
    John Nye feels that one of my two brief specific references to his work “leaves the impression that my work downplays the problems of individual differences in taste or social institutions by dismissing them out of hand”. Let me assure him that he is unduly alarmed, since virtually all readers will read into the passage that he quotes only what I intended and, indeed, what Nye himself intended - that if he or anyone else had found evidence that firm size (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  • “The Conflation of Productivity and Efficiency in Economics and Economic History”: A Comment.John Vincent Nye - 1990 - Economics and Philosophy 6 (1):147-152.
    In a recent article, Edward Saraydar takes economists and economic historians to task for equating productivity and efficiency in comparative economic analysis. Although I found his thesis interesting, I was a bit surprised to see selected remarks from my article on firm size in nineteenth-century France used to frame his criticism of productivity comparisons as a means of making prescriptive statements. The passages selected may mislead the reader as to the nature of my arguments. Let me quote Saraydar on this: (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  • The Economic Efficiency and Equity of Abortion.Thomas J. Meeks - 1990 - Economics and Philosophy 6 (1):95-138.
    On the face of it, the protracted public controversy over abortion in the United States and elsewhere might seem to rest on intractable normative questions inaccessible to economic analysis. But an influential early essay in the now sizable philosophical literature on the subject suggests otherwise. Judith Jarvis Thomson disarmingly inclined toward the view that “the fetus has already become a human person well before birth”,. presumably with all the rights pertaining thereto. She denied, however, that such rights necessarily include use (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   1 citation  
  • Nietzsche on Slavery: Exploring the Meaning and Relevance of Nietzsche’s Perspective.Dmitri Safronov - 2019 - International Political Anthropology 2 (2):21-45.
    Nietzsche is absent from today’s growing debate on slavery past and present. In this article I argue that his views on the subject add a pertinent, if challenging, dimension to this wide-ranging discussion. Nietzsche’s analysis is capable of contributing to our understanding of this multifaceted phenomenon in a number of respects. I look at Nietzsche’s use of the controversial notions of slavery, understood both historically and in the context of modern society, to explore such central concerns of political anthropology as (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  • Natural Cybernetics and Mathematical History: The Principle of Least Choice in History.Vasil Penchev - 2020 - Cultural Anthropology (Elsevier: SSRN) 5 (23):1-44.
    The paper follows the track of a previous paper “Natural cybernetics of time” in relation to history in a research of the ways to be mathematized regardless of being a descriptive humanitarian science withal investigating unique events and thus rejecting any repeatability. The pathway of classical experimental science to be mathematized gradually and smoothly by more and more relevant mathematical models seems to be inapplicable. Anyway quantum mechanics suggests another pathway for mathematization; considering the historical reality as dual or “complimentary” (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  • Reparations, Once Again.Wilton D. Alston & Walter E. Block - 2008 - Human Rights Review 9 (3):379-392.
    Reparations whether to blacks for slavery, or to Indians for land theft, or to settle any number of other conflicts, has an interesting political background. Analysts on the left, who are usually no friend of private property rights, nevertheless rely on this doctrine to support their case for reparations. Those on the right, in contrast, who supposedly defend the institution of property rights, jettison them when it comes to reparations. It is only libertarians, such as the present authors, who both (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  • The world political economy and the future of the U.S. labor market.Manuel Yevenes - 1985 - World Futures 21 (1):147-157.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  • Women's work in the U.S.: Variations by regions. [REVIEW]Carolyn Sachs - 1985 - Agriculture and Human Values 2 (1):31-39.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   1 citation  
  • Rational choice, functional selection and empty black boxes.Philip Pettit - 2000 - Journal of Economic Methodology 7 (1):33-57.
    In order to vindicate rational-choice theory as a mode of explaining social patterns in general - social patterns beyond the narrow range of economic behaviour - we have to recognize the legitimacy of explaining the resilience of certain patterns of behaviour: that is, explaining, not necessarily why they emerged or have been sustained, but why they are robust and reliable. And once we allow the legitimacy of explaining resilience, then we can see how functionalist theory may also serve us well (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   18 citations  
  • The denial of slavery in contemporary American sociology.Orlando Patterson - 2019 - Theory and Society 48 (6):903-914.
    American sociology has largely neglected enslavement as a topic of study, despite slavery’s being one of the most foundational, pervasive, and far-reaching social institutions in the West. In this paper I explain this scholarly neglect as stemming from three factors. First, disciplinary parochialism has blinded US sociologists to the complex interweaving of enslavement with the systems of oppression that sociology has decided to care about. Second, presentism, an ahistorical “account” of the past that culminates in a preference for present-day events (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  • Cliometrics, child labor, and the industrial revolution.Jane Humphries - 1999 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 13 (3-4):269-283.
    Abstract Ten years ago, Clark Nardinelli shocked conventional historians by reinterpreting child labor as a sensible response to the Industrial Revolution. Nardinelli's exculpation of child labor follows front the way in which he deploys neoclassical economic theory. How relevant is his neoclassical model to the early industrial economy, and how realistic is methodological individualism to the decisions that sent young children into the appalling work places of early industrial Britain? Rather than seeing neoclassical economics as a substitute for historical judgment, (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  • Ethics, profession, and rational choice.Ananda Das Gupta - 2016 - Asian Journal of Business Ethics 5 (1-2):53-60.
    Human development can be seen as the process of giving more effective expression to human values. Modern business philosophy has a certain viewpoint or perspective on human potential based on the secular humanistic values of the west and the scientific theories on the nature of man and his evolution. We are bound to welcome the New Paradigm in Business because it opens the path for a decisive step forward in evolution from an authoritarian, mechanistic, Taylorian era to a freer and (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  • The Conflation of Productivity and Efficiency in Economics and Economic History.Edward Saraydar - 1989 - Economics and Philosophy 5 (1):55.
    The literature of comparative economics as well as economic history is replete with references to productivity differences as reflecting relative efficiency in production. In socialist economics, for example, the longevity of the relative-productivity/relative-efficiency theme is apparent from Abram Bergson's early survey where, commenting on a productivity debate that had already been going on for over twenty years, he identified “the only issue outstanding” as the question “which is more efficient, socialism or capitalism?” The issue has continued to be addressed vigorously (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   5 citations