Switch to: Citations

Add references

You must login to add references.
  1. Why do people cooperate?Ken Binmore - 2006 - Politics, Philosophy and Economics 5 (1):81-96.
    Can people be relied upon to be nice to each other? Thomas Hobbes famously did not think so, but his view that rational cooperation does not require that people be nice has never been popular. The debate has continued to simmer since Joseph Butler took up the Hobbist gauntlet in 1725. This article defends the modern version of Hobbism derived largely from game theory against a new school of Butlerians who call themselves behavioral economists. It is agreed that the experimental (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   26 citations  
  • (1 other version)Unto Others: The Evolution and Psychology of Unselfish Behavior.Paul E. Griffiths - 2002 - Mind 111 (441):178-182.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   239 citations  
  • Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed.Jared Diamond - 2007 - Environmental Values 16 (1):133-135.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   130 citations  
  • Social intelligence, human intelligence and niche construction.Kim Sterelny - 2007 - In Nathan Emery, Nicola Clayton & Chris Frith (eds.), Social Intelligence: From Brain to Culture. Oxford University Press.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   51 citations  
  • Ethnobiological classification.Brent Berlin - 1978 - In Eleanor Rosch & Barbara Bloom Lloyd (eds.), Cognition and Categorization. Lawrence Elbaum Associates. pp. 9--26.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   62 citations  
  • (1 other version)Reciprocity: Weak or strong? What punishment experiments do (and do not) demonstrate.Francesco Guala - 2012 - Behavioral and Brain Sciences 35 (1):1-15.
    Economists and biologists have proposed a distinction between two mechanisms – “strong” and “weak” reciprocity – that may explain the evolution of human sociality. Weak reciprocity theorists emphasize the benefits of long-term cooperation and the use of low-cost strategies to deter free-riders. Strong reciprocity theorists, in contrast, claim that cooperation in social dilemma games can be sustained by costly punishment mechanisms, even in one-shot and finitely repeated games. To support this claim, they have generated a large body of evidence concerning (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   54 citations  
  • (1 other version)Partner choice, fairness, and the extension of morality.Nicolas Baumard, Jean-Baptiste André & Dan Sperber - 2013 - Behavioral and Brain Sciences 36 (1):102-122.
    Our discussion of the commentaries begins, at the evolutionary level, with issues raised by our account of the evolution of morality in terms of partner-choice mutualism. We then turn to the cognitive level and the characterization and workings of fairness. In a final section, we discuss the degree to which our fairness-based approach to morality extends to norms that are commonly considered moral even though they are distinct from fairness.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   96 citations  
  • Life in Interesting Times: Cooperation and Collective Action in the Holocene.Kim Sterelny - 2013 - In Kim Sterelny, Richard Joyce, Brett Calcott & Ben Fraser (eds.), Cooperation and its Evolution. MIT Press.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   13 citations  
  • Moral Origins: The Evolution of Virtue, Altruism, and Shame.Christopher Boehm - 2010 - Basic Books.
    Darwin's inner voice -- Living the virtuous life -- Of altruism and free riders -- Knowing our immediate predecessors -- Resurrecting some venerable ancestors -- A natural Garden of Eden -- The positive side of social selection -- Learning morals across the generations -- Work of the moral majority -- Pleistocene ups, downs, and crashes -- Testing the selection-by-reputation hypothesis -- The evolution of morals -- Epilogue: humanity's moral future.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   74 citations  
  • The Cultural Origins of Human Cognition.Michael Tomasello - 1999 - Harvard University Press.
    Ambitious and elegant, this book builds a bridge between evolutionary theory and cultural psychology. Michael Tomasello is one of the very few people to have done systematic research on the cognitive capacities of both nonhuman primates and human children. The Cultural Origins of Human Cognition identifies what the differences are, and suggests where they might have come from. -/- Tomasello argues that the roots of the human capacity for symbol-based culture, and the kind of psychological development that takes place within (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   641 citations  
  • Darwinian Populations and Natural Selection.Peter Godfrey-Smith - 2009 - Oxford, GB: Oxford University Press.
    The book presents a new way of understanding Darwinism and evolution by natural selection, combining work in biology, philosophy, and other fields.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   317 citations  
  • Unto Others: The Evolution and Psychology of Unselfish Behavior.Elliott Sober & David Sloan Wilson - 1998 - Harvard University Press.
    The authors demonstrate that unselfish behavior is in fact an important feature of both biological and human nature. Their book provides a panoramic view of altruism throughout the animal kingdom--from self-sacrificing parasites to the human capacity for selflessness--even as it explains the evolutionary sense of such behavior.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   494 citations  
  • Mutual aid; a factor of evolution.Peter Kropotkin - unknown
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   82 citations  
  • “Economic man” in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies.Joseph Henrich, Robert Boyd, Samuel Bowles, Colin Camerer, Ernst Fehr, Herbert Gintis, Richard McElreath, Michael Alvard, Abigail Barr, Jean Ensminger, Natalie Smith Henrich, Kim Hill, Francisco Gil-White, Michael Gurven, Frank W. Marlowe & John Q. Patton - 2005 - Behavioral and Brain Sciences 28 (6):795-815.
    Researchers from across the social sciences have found consistent deviations from the predictions of the canonical model of self-interest in hundreds of experiments from around the world. This research, however, cannot determine whether the uniformity results from universal patterns of human behavior or from the limited cultural variation available among the university students used in virtually all prior experimental work. To address this, we undertook a cross-cultural study of behavior in ultimatum, public goods, and dictator games in a range of (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   131 citations  
  • (2 other versions)The evolution of altruistic punishment.Rob Boyd - manuscript
    Robert Boyd*†, Herbert Gintis‡, Samuel Bowles§, and Peter J. Richerson¶.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   77 citations  
  • Passions Within Reason: The Strategic Role of Emotions.Robert Frank - 1988 - Norton.
    In this book, I make use of an idea from economics to suggest how noble human tendencies might not only have survived the ruthless pressures of the material world, but actually have been nurtured by them.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   517 citations  
  • Game Theory and the Social Contract.Ken Binmore - 1994 - MIT Press.
    Binmore argues that game theory provides a systematic tool for investigating ethical matters.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   102 citations  
  • A Paleolithic Reciprocation Crisis: Symbols, Signals, and Norms.Kim Sterelny - 2014 - Biological Theory 9 (1):65-77.
    Within paleoanthropology, the origin of behavioral modernity is a famous problem. Very large-brained hominins have lived for around half a million years, yet social lives resembling those known from the ethnographic record appeared perhaps 100,000 years ago. Why did it take 400,000 years for humans to start acting like humans? In this article, I argue that part of the solution is a transition in the economic foundations of cooperation from a relatively undemanding form, to one that imposed much more stress (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   20 citations  
  • (1 other version)Reciprocity: Weak or strong? What punishment experiments do (and do not) demonstrate.Francesco Guala - 2012 - Behavioral and Brain Sciences 35 (1):1-15.
    Economists and biologists have proposed a distinction between two mechanisms – “strong” and “weak” reciprocity – that may explain the evolution of human sociality. Weak reciprocity theorists emphasize the benefits of long-term cooperation and the use of low-cost strategies to deter free-riders. Strong reciprocity theorists, in contrast, claim that cooperation in social dilemma games can be sustained by costly punishment mechanisms, even in one-shot and finitely repeated games. To support this claim, they have generated a large body of evidence concerning (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   14 citations  
  • The origins of war. [REVIEW]Keith F. Otterbein - 1997 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 11 (2):251-277.
    In War Before Civilization, Lawrence H. Keeley argues that prehistoric as well as primitive mankind was more warlike than has been recognized by most scholars. Such scholars subscribe, according to Keeley, to “the myth of the peaceful savage,” the subtitle of his book. But Keeley, who leads a long list of Hawks, has replaced this myth with another, the “myth of the warlike savage.” Anthropologists who argue that serious warfare arose only after the rise of the state and civilization understate (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   6 citations  
  • Social norms or social preferences?Ken Binmore - 2010 - Mind and Society 9 (2):139-157.
    Some behavioral economists argue that the honoring of social norms can be adequately modeled as the optimization of social utility functions in which the welfare of others appears as an explicit argument. This paper suggests that the large experimental claims made for social utility functions are premature at best, and that social norms are better studied as equilibrium selection devices that evolved for use in games that are seldom studied in economics laboratories.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   16 citations  
  • Evolution and the levels of selection.Samir Okasha - 2006 - New York: Oxford University Press.
    Does natural selection act primarily on individual organisms, on groups, on genes, or on whole species? The question of levels of selection - on which biologists and philosophers have long disagreed - is central to evolutionary theory and to the philosophy of biology. Samir Okasha's comprehensive analysis gives a clear account of the philosophical issues at stake in the current debate.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   278 citations  
  • Evolution and the Levels of Selection.Samir Okasha - 2009 - Critica 41 (123):162-170.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   287 citations  
  • The Stag Hunt and the Evolution of Social Structure.Brian Skyrms - 2003 - Cambridge University Press.
    Brian Skyrms, author of the successful Evolution of the Social Contract has written a sequel. The book is a study of ideas of cooperation and collective action. The point of departure is a prototypical story found in Rousseau's A Discourse on Inequality. Rousseau contrasts the pay-off of hunting hare where the risk of non-cooperation is small but the reward is equally small, against the pay-off of hunting the stag where maximum cooperation is required but where the reward is so much (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   195 citations  
  • Rethinking Paleoanthropology.Peter J. Richerson - unknown
    Ongoing advances in paleoclimatology and paleoecology are producing an ever more detailed picture of the environments in which our species evolved. This picture is important to understanding the processes by which our large brain evolved. Our large brain and its productions—toolmaking, complex social institutions, language, art, religion—are our most striking differences from our closest living relatives. Indeed, humans are unique in the animal world for our brain size relative to body mass and in the elaboration of our cultures. We are (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   8 citations  
  • Cooperative Breeding in Birds: Toward a Richer Conceptual Framework.Andrew Cockburn - 2013 - In Kim Sterelny, Richard Joyce, Brett Calcott & Ben Fraser (eds.), Cooperation and its Evolution. MIT Press.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   1 citation  
  • Tribal S Ocial Instin Cts a Nd the Cultural Evolution O F Institutions to Solv E Col Lecti Ve Action Problems.Peter Richerson - unknown
    Human social life is uniquely complex and diverse. Much of that complexity consists of culturally transmitted ideas and skills that underpin the operation of institutions that structure our social life. Considerable theoretical and empirical work has been devoted to the role of cultural evolutionary processes in the evolution of institutions. The most persistent controversy has been over the role of cultural group selection and gene-culture coevolution in early human populations the Pleistocene. We argue that cultural group selection and related cultural (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   23 citations  
  • The Stag Hunt and the Evolution of Social Structure. [REVIEW]Robert van Rooij - 2007 - Studia Logica 85 (1):133-138.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   98 citations  
  • A Biology of Moral Systems.Richard D. Alexander - 1990 - Behavior and Philosophy 18 (2):89-96.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   9 citations  
  • (1 other version)A Cooperative Species: Human Reciprocity and its Evolution, S. Bowles and H. Gintis. Princeton University Press, 2011, xii + 262 pages. [REVIEW]Benoît Dubreuil - 2012 - Economics and Philosophy 28 (3):423-428.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  • The Righteous Mind: Why Good People are Divided by Politics and Religion.Jonathan Haidt - unknown
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   554 citations  
  • The causes and scope of political egalitarianism during the Last Glacial: a multi-disciplinary perspective.Doron Shultziner, Thomas Stevens, Martin Stevens, Brian A. Stewart, Rebecca J. Hannagan & Giulia Saltini-Semerari - 2010 - Biology and Philosophy 25 (3):319-346.
    This paper reviews and synthesizes emerging multi-disciplinary evidence toward understanding the development of social and political organization in the Last Glacial. Evidence for the prevalence and scope of political egalitarianism is reviewed and the biological, social, and environmental influences on this mode of human organization are further explored. Viewing social and political organization in the Last Glacial in a much wider, multi-disciplinary context provides the footing for coherent theory building and hypothesis testing by which to further explore human political systems. (...)
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   4 citations  
  • Review of Robert H. Frank: Passions Within Reason: The Strategic Role of Emotions[REVIEW]Alan Hamlin - 1991 - Ethics 101 (2):411-412.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   220 citations  
  • (1 other version)No Title available: Reviews.Benoît Dubreuil - 2012 - Economics and Philosophy 28 (3):423-428.
    Book Reviews Benoît Dubreuil, Economics and Philosophy, FirstView Article.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  • (2 other versions)The evolution of altruistic punishment.Robert Boyd, Herbert Gintis, Samuel Bowles, Peter Richerson & J. - 2003 - Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 100 (6):3531-3535.
    Download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   88 citations